Introduction to "Economic Democracy""There is always a time-lag of generations between the appearance of a seminal idea, and the possibility of its widespread acceptance by minds which can be opened to it, on a large scale, only by the heavy pressure of events which have been correctly anticipated." INTRODUCTION by Geoffrey Dobbs, Bangor Wales. May 1974 It is one thing for the teacher to write a foreword to
the pupil's work, as C. H. Douglas once did for mine, and quite another, even
twenty-two years after the author's death, for the pupil to introduce the master's;
but I am glad to undertake this, not only because it is an honour to be asked
to do so by the author's daughter and copy-right-holder, but also because some
introductory explanation has now become very necessary for a book written in the
idiom of fifty years ago, some of which has been changed or even inverted in meaning,
although its substance remains singularly up-to-date and critically relevant to
the circum stances of the present day. It must be remembered, however, that although The New Age was in contemporary terms a leading 'socialist' or 'progressive' journal - even 'avant garde' in its day - the meaning of those terms has now been changed, sometimes to the point of inversion, after half a century in which the world has been rushing down the other fork of the cross-roads at which Douglas and his contemporaries stood, having ignored the signpost which he set up, and having now discovered, to its bitter cost, that it has taken the wrong path. It is therefore particularly appropriate that this book, long out of print, should be republished, and that signpost set up again,, so that a disillusioned world can realise that there exists an alternative to disaster, though not without a radical change in the sort of thinking which now accepts the centralisation of power as 'progressive', and condemns its distribution as 'reactionary'. Even before Douglas appeared on the scene, Orage and The New Age had chosen the path of freedom and turned their backs on collectivist State Socialism, that is, on the socialism of the will-to-power, as well as the soul-destroying wage-slavery of Capitalist mass-production. Under the heading of Guild Socialism they were inclined to look backwards to the craftsmanship of mediaeval times, and to reject all science and technology as of the devil. Douglas supplied just what these people lacked. For although The New Age was the forum for the leading literary and political writers of the day, it was then, even more than now, taken for granted that politics and economics were subjects for men of words. It was unheard of for someone with practical knowledge and experience of the actual processes of industry and accountancy to take a hand. In this,
Douglas was as far ahead of his time as he proved to be in other ways. An engineer,
with a wide experience of practical responsibility in many parts of the world,
including the unique experience of drawing up the plans and specifications for
the electrical work on the Post Office Tube (one of the earliest examples of automation
in the history of engineering) he had spent the last two years of the First World
War as Assistant Superintendent of the Government Aircraft Factory at Farnborough.
In this capacity he brought an original mind to the question of the factory's
cost accountancy - a mind which thought first in terms of the practical realities
of production for use, and then considered the book-keeping or financial arrangements
as a secondary convenience, much as a railway engineer might consider the railway
ticket system. This might seem obvious, but it completely inverted the accepted
manner of thinking which treats the whole industrial process as if it existed
for financial ends, whether for profits or for employment and wages. Douglas's
first article in the English Review of December 1918: The Delusion of Super-production,
would have been still a little ahead of its time if published in 1968; and his
recognition of the social responsibility of the scientist and technologist, and
of the colossal sabotage and waste of real resources and energy involved in our
financially dominated economic system, have yet to receive their due, even now
when, at long last, events have begun to move public opinion in this direction. It
is not, for instance, the widely held ownership of the means of production by
'private' (i.e. free, independent) people which creates an exploited proletariat
and the consequent class struggle. On the contrary, the more 'common' such ownership
is, the greater the freedom of the worker in choosing his employer, and the less
'common' the less freedom, until it disappears altogether when the State become
sole employer, under the abstract slogan: 'Common Ownership'. There
are two opposite directions in which a movement which sets out to protect and
liberate the workers can move from this situation. The will-to-freedom would work
towards the elimination of a proletariat through decreasing dependence upon employment,
as productivity increases, decreasing the importance of labour as a factor in
production; and also with the increasing need to conserve resources and avoid
waste through unnecessary employment in the production of unwanted and unneeded
products. The power-socialist
views with even greater hostility than the power-capitalist the possibility of
an increasingly independent worker, capable of making his own bargain with the
employer, and with no need to surrender the control over his labour to a Union
Leader. In consequence the Big Unions have grown into labour monopolies with far
more terrifying powers over the workers than the employer holds; and have now
become armies, organised to demand money with menaces, not merely against the
employers, but, ironically enough in the 'public' sector, against the whole community-a
strange outcome from a socialism that used to talk about working to serve the
community and not for gain. Unfortunately, some of them do not recognise the anarchy of 'continuous
revolution', which they have been led to suppose will avert this State, as an
essential part of the fear-mechanism which is used to introduce it. It is necessary
to be far more radical; to get down to the real causes; and to take the rejected
path to freedom with Douglas. 'Property'
having now become 'the right to get money from' and 'the people' a collective
mass represented by the Government, the way is now open for the complete inversion
of 'common property' to mean the expropriation of all actual people, while the
real powers of ownership pass to the ruling oligarchy and its dependent bureaucracy. Perhaps
some examples will be helpful. Air, for instance, is a 'natural resource' which
is unique in being common property in the most complete sense-available to everyone,
everywhere, at all times, since all have the means for its exploitation in their
lungs. If it were to become 'common property' in the State Socialist sense, it
would, of course, be vested in the Government, and everyone would lose the right
to breathe freely, exploiting for their own personal gain the property of 'The
People'. Land, on the other hand, is a resource of a different nature, In
that it is fixed and local, it is also a 'mixed' resource; in part a universal
essential, but in part also a form of capital of no direct use per se, but only
as a vital factor in the production of necessities such as food, clothing and
timber. As common owners of the land we all need to be able to walk upon it and
to traverse it for purposes of travel and recreation, wherever this does not infringe
more important forms of ownership. We also all need to dwell and to make our homes
upon a particular piece of land, and it is here that the contrast between the
aims of the will-to-power and the will-to-freedom is at its most obvious. The same applies to coal, oil, or minerals in the earth's
crust. What use could most of us make of a coal seam, a copper deposit, or oil
or gas under the North Sea? To talk of common ownership of these in the real sense
is meaningless nonsense. We cannot exercise the rights of ownership until they
have been converted and made available to us in usable form. Exactly the same
considerations apply to the ownership of the capital equipment of industry required
for the processing of these resources for our use. What real (not monetary) use
could we make of a coal mine, an oil rig, or a steel mill? We are said to
live in a 'Consumer Society' suffering from the disease of 'consumptionism' due
to the greed of the common people as consumers. But this puts things upside down.
'Productionism' or 'employmentism' would be better names for the disease, for
we are passing increasingly under producers' control, the consumers, whose greed
is much exploited in the process, being force-fed with the by-products of an industry
which is primarily concerned with the provision of work and the distribution of
money. The necessity for consumer control of production is
the necessary background for an understanding of Douglas's monetary analysis and
proposals, and much confusion has been caused by critics who have not grasped
this, but who used to maintain that he had mistaken a temporary shortage of purchasing
power due to deflation for a permanent deficiency in the system. In fact, Douglas
never said that our producer-dominated credit distribution system could never
distribute money to buy the goods wanted, but that it could not do so without
producing what was not wanted, and with accelerating waste and sabotage. Douglas alone has analysed
the situation correctly and shown us the way out; and events have proved him to
have been right, and his critics wrong. Distribution, he pointed out, should be
a function of work accomplished, not of work in progress. That means that the
people, collectively, ought to be able to meet the accumulated costs of all the
goods they want as they come on the market, without mortgaging the future. It must be remembered that Economic Democracy was Douglas's first
book; the prentice effort of a mind already mature, but which was to grow in depth
and incisiveness for another thirty years. It is certainly his most 'difficult'
book; it is incredibly condensed, and it took a mind of the calibre of A. R. Orage's
to grasp its significance when it was written. Douglas once told my wife that
Economic Democracy was the last of his books that he wanted to see re-published,
and he is understood to have had thoughts about re-writing parts of it, notably
Chapter 8 with its 'purely idealistic' scheme at the end, which was admittedly
not practicable at the time, in contrast with the proposals for redistribution
of the National Debt in Chapter 9, and for the Just Price in Chapter 10. These
may be seen as early examples of proposals embodying the principles of consumer
control, produced under First World War conditions of centralisation, for application
in the post-War situation. Here, then, are some of the reasons why I have thought that this first book now needs an introductory Chapter to put it into the background of the late Twentieth Century, and to dispel some of the garbled versions of Douglas's ideas which have been put about in the meantime. The Delusion of Super-Production, Douglas's first article, published in the English Review of December 1918, has been added as an appendix. It is difficult to imagine anything more prophetic or relevant to the situation of the 1970's. (Now the 2000s.) There is always a time-lag of generations between the appearance of a seminal idea, and the possibility of its widespread acceptance by minds which can be opened to it, on a large scale, only by the heavy pressure of events which have been correctly anticipated. It appears that this time is now approaching for the opening of minds to Douglas's ideas. In the 1920's and 1930's many people could see their application to the situation of 'poverty amid plenty' through mass-unemployment among unsold goods and unused productive power. But most people could see no further when, as Douglas so frequently predicted, this 'problem' was 'solved' by the vast super-production of War, and Keynesian economics brought in the era of accelerating super-production via continuous inflation and 'employmentism'. At long last it is being realised that this cannot go on indefinitely; that even this rich planet with its continual shower of energy from the Sun, cannot endure without impoverishment, the wasting of its resources at an accelerating rate upon purposes other than the precise requirements of the people who live on it - purposes such as the distribution of book-entries and money-tokens, or the imposition of the will of a handful of controllers of production. Already the environmental Movement has become a 'bandwaggon' which has been taken over by producer interests concerned to exploit (and often to exaggerate) the scarcities they are making, so as to tighten still further the dictatorship of the producer and distributor over the people they are supposed to serve. In conclusion, it may be said, literally and solemnly, that no efforts to deal with this economic dictatorship, or to avert the environmental crisis which it is bringing about, can hope for success on the scale necessary to avoid disaster, unless and until prejudice is laid aside, and the fundamental revolution in ideas which was inaugurated by this book is accepted and put into effect. ABOUT THE AUTHOR OF ECONOMIC DEMOCRACY The late Clifford Hugh
Douglas, M.I.Mech.E., M.I.E.E., consulting engineer, economist, author, and founder
of the Social Credit Movement, was born in 1879 and died in 1952. One of his most interesting jobs, just before the 1914 War, was that of conducting preliminary experimental work and preparing plans and specifications for the electrical work on the Post Office Tube in London, with later supervision of the installation of plant in what was to be one of the earliest examples of complete automation in the history of engineering. While there were no physical difficulties about the work, he used to get orders from time to time to slow it up and pay off the men. When the War came, however, he noticed that there was no longer any difficulty about getting money for anything the Government wanted. It appears that he was sent to Farnborough in 1916 to sort out 'a certain amount of muddle' in the Aircraft Factory's accounts, so that he had to go very carefully into the costing. This he did by introducing what were then known as 'tabulating machines' - an approach which anticipated the much later use of computers, and which drew his attention to the much faster rate at which the factory was generating costs as compared with the rate at which it was distributing incomes in the form of wages and salaries. Could this be true of every factory or commercial business? Douglas then collected Information
from over 100 businesses in Great Britain, and found that, in every case except
in businesses heading for bankruptcy, the total costs always exceeded the sums
paid out in wages, salaries and dividends. It followed that only a part of the
final product could be distributed through the incomes disbursed by its production,
and, moreover, a diminishing part as industrial processes lengthened and became
more complex and increased the ratio of overheads to current wages. This original engineer's
approach, which regarded the monetary system much as Douglas, a former railway
engineer, had regarded the ticket system, as a mere book-keeping convenience for
the efficient distribution of the product, was completely alien and unacceptable
to the economic theorists of the day. Only one Professor of Economics (Professor
Irvine of Sydney) expressed agreement with it, and he resigned his post shortly
afterwards. When the Great Depression of the 1930's grimly confirmed Douglas's diagnosis and gave him a world-wide reputation and following, his critics explained that he had mistaken a temporary lapse for a permanent defect in the monetary system; but subsequent events have, by now, so continuously fulfilled his predictions that this criticism is no longer credible. Despite rejection by the Economic Establishment of the day, Douglas was
called upon to give evidence before the Canadian Banking Enquiry in 1923 and the
Macmillan Committee in 1930, and undertook several World Tours in which he addressed
many gatherings, especially in Canada, Australia and New Zealand, and also at
the World Engineering Congress in Tokyo in 1929. It
should be placed on historical record, as a precedent, that two 'provincial dividends'
of little more than token value, were nevertheless paid at one period to the citizens
of the Province, and that, while still acting under the advice of Douglas's representative,
the province paid its way without further borrowing, and drastically reduced the
Provincial debt. In 1934 a Social Credit Secretariat was
formed under his Chairmanship, which started an Electoral Campaign involving the
use of the vote for purposes desired by the electors rather than by Parliament
or the political Parties. This was followed by a highly successful Local Objectives
Campaign along similar non-party lines, and a Lower Rates and Assessments Campaign
which saved the British ratepayers many millions of pounds without loss of services,
by reducing loan charges. In the final phase of his life, roughly from 1939 to his death in 1952, Douglas consolidated his ideas in depth, contrasting very clearly the philosophy which underlies them with that which activates the Monopoly of Credit. Although the best known of them, which have already exercised considerable influence in the World, lie in the economic sphere: the concepts of real credit, the increment of association and the cultural inheritance, and the proposals of the National Dividend and the Just or Compensated Price-his political ideas, though as yet little known, are if anything of greater importance. They were always worked out with a characteristic practicality, taking account of the feed-back from the course of events. No one else has thrown so much light on the true nature of democracy, as distinct from the numerical product of the ballot box; on the need for decentralised control of policy and hierarchical control of administration; on the freedom to choose one thing at a time, on the right to contract out, on the Voters' Policy and the Voters' Veto. In his last address, given in London to the Constitutional Research Association in 1947, he put forward his last proposal for the rehabilitation of democracy: the Responsible Vote, in which the financial consequences of his open electoral choice would be, for a time, differentially paid for by the voter in proportion to his income-a literally revolutionary suggestion which demands an inversion of current ideas about anonymous, irresponsible, numerical voting. Hugh Gaitskell, a former
Leader of the Labour Party, once sarcastically described Douglas as 'a religious
rather than a scientific reformer'. Perhaps he was more right than he knew! In his view, a 'philosophy', i.e. a conception of
the universe, always expresses itself as a 'policy'-a distinctive long-term course
of action directed towards ends determined by that 'philosophy'. The policies
of centralisation and monopoly now being imposed upon the World through the closely
related agencies of Finance-Capitalism and Marxist Socialism derive from a 'philosophy'
fundamentally different from, and opposed to, that of Trinitarian Christianity,
which was, however imperfectly, expressed in our Constitution, our Common Law,
and the progress towards personal freedom which had been made, especially, in
Britain and the Commonwealth. |
© Published by the Australian League of Rights, P.O. Box 27 Happy Valley, SA 5159 |