THE MONEY POWER VERSUS DEMOCRACY by Eric D. Butler (written during WWII)I have written this book because I believe that the fate of civilisation, as we understand it, depends upon a more widespread knowledge of the principles of real democracy. Democracy is being challenged all over the world. It must answer the challenge or die. How many of us have thought about this matter? Perhaps some do not desire to think. Does the average citizen know what a real democracy is? No.
We ask thousands of our young men to sacrifice their lives on the battlefield in order that democracy may survive; is it too much to ask those of us at home to also make some sacrifice, a sacrifice of those worn-out shibboleths and prejudices responsible for the growing chaos?
The present situation is a challenge to every man and woman. Dare we ignore it?
INTRODUCTION More people than ever are thinking; thinking harder than ever before. The whole world has been thrown into a state of turmoil and confusion, and the old order is obviously crumbling. What will emerge from this state of flux? Can the Anglo-Saxon people lead the world back to sanity? Has democracy failed? These, and many similar questions, are being asked today. Let me say at the outset that I am firmly convinced that democracy is the only satisfactory basis upon which a society for free individuals can be built. Democracy is more than a political science; it is a complete philosophy, covering every phase of human activity. Unfortunately, very few have an accurate conception of what democracy really means; otherwise there would be no suggestion that it has failed. The world conflict which we see today enters into every aspect of human affairs - military, political and economic. This conflict is, broadly speaking, a final clash between totalitarianism and democracy. Basically, it is an issue which has been fought throughout past centuries. It has now reached a crisis, the outcome of which will decide the future of mankind for centuries to come. It cannot be ignored; we must think about it, we must clearly understand the problem. Having clearly understood it, we can then decide upon the correct line of action required to REALLY avert disaster. It will be my endeavour in this book to clearly outline the entire subject, to present the case for democracy, and to show how it can be made fully effective; all in a simple and compact manner, for the benefit of the average busy citizen. THE NATURE OF REAL DEMOCRACY A Democracy can be defined as a society in which the will of the majority of the electors prevails; or, a society in which a majority of the people get what they want. “The people who govern are the people who get what they want.” Real power should reside with the electors.
The above statement by Byrne is worthy of close study. The soundness of any society must be judged by the individuals comprising that society. Abstract terms such as “collective security” mean nothing. There can be no security of any kind unless individuals have security. THE MONEY POWER AND DEMOCRACY In spite of inspired propaganda to the contrary it is becoming more and more obvious as a result of the present world crisis that the major cause of the troubles which have brought insecurity and misery to the individuals of every nation resides in false ideas concerning the nature and function of money. Although the world seems to be full of many different problems, a little examination of the facts will indicate to the unprejudiced that these problems are merely the effects of a money problem. It is impossible for anyone to have any real understanding of the issues facing civilisation today unless he is prepared to learn something about the power of money. Let us recall the following statement made by the late Arthur Kitson, noted British inventor and engineer, who fought the Money Power for nearly 50 years:
Now compare that with the two following statements. The first was made by Mr. Philip A. Benson, President of the American Bankers’ Association in a speech at Milwaukee, on June 8, 1939, and was quoted in the “New York Times” of June 11, 1939. He said:
The second statement was made in 1936 by the late Vincent C. Vickers, a former director of the Bank of England:
Increasing numbers of people are asking, ‘Is it necessary or right that we should be governed by money power?’ The future welfare of the money industry as it is at present constituted, depends entirely upon its own power to crush out the human impulse to go forward and upon its ability to override the will of the people and so govern the world. For how long can they succeed with such a policy? They are so few.” THE PROBLEM OF DISTRIBUTION The basic economic problem which has confronted civilisation for many years is one of distribution. Poverty amidst plenty has become a common expression. This unsolved problem of distributing the fruits of science has been the greatest factor in increasing our national ills - while the rise of totalitarianism has been the direct result of similar social ills in other countries. The international fight for markets with increasing international friction is the result of the failure of the nations to distribute the results of production to their people. Distribution depends upon money. There is a gap between production and consumption. The Southampton Chamber of Commerce summed up the problem in the following statement:
DICTATORSHIP OF RIGHT OR LEFT? Dr. C. E. M. Joad, writing on the failure of the present system of distribution and its effects upon the democratic system of government, in his book, “Liberty Today,” says:
All over the world we have seen this swing towards dictatorship of various forms because of that unsolved problem. It remains for the British people to show that democracy will allow a constitutional solution of the problem. That is one of the main reasons why the military challenge of those nations who have abandoned any semblance of democratic government must be met. PRIVATE BANKS MANUFACTURE MONEY Distribution under our modern system of economy is dependent upon the amount of effective purchasing-power in the hands of the public. The subject of purchasing-power cannot be discussed unless we are familiar with the source from which it comes. That source is the private banks. Banks manufacture money just as boot-manufacturers manufacture boots. Not very long ago, the majority of the people thought that banks only lent their depositors’ money. The whole question of money seemed to be shrouded in such mystery that one would have thought that it was some peculiar substance over which man had no control. Thank goodness we have moved forward a little since then and that an ever-increasing number of people are beginning to understand that the bulk of our money supply today consists of no more than figures in ledgers operated upon by cheques. It is only a matter of bookkeeping. Let the following authorities indicate the true position:
Mr. J. M. Keynes, the noted economist, says:
Mr. R. G. Hawtrey, Assistant Secretary to the British Treasury, put the matter as briefly and clearly as possible when in his book, “Trade Depression and the Way Out,” he wrote: Professor Soddy has written upon the matter as follows:
Hon. Reginald McKenna, Chairman of the Midland Bank, summed up the position in the following terms:
On another occasion, McKenna said:
Professor F. Soddy, F.R.S., writes in his book, “Wealth”:
WHAT IS MONEY IF IT IS NOT WEALTH? The simple facts about money cannot be stated too often. There has been no greater delusion, keeping man a mental and physical slave, than the idea that money is wealth. Money only represents a claim to wealth. It has taken many forms through the ages, from cowrie shells to our present cheque system. Possibly the best orthodox definition of money is given by Professor Walker: In view of the fact that the people have collectively produced the real wealth, which alone gives any kind of money its value, it is a remarkable thing that they are going further into debt to private groups who do no more than create the claims to the wealth. However, this is so. Furthermore, taxation must be progressively increased to meet the interest charges on the debts being incurred. In dealing with the money question and its relationship to democracy, I would mention that we are not concerned with the administration of the present banking system. As a matter of fact, the present banking administration is practically perfect. That is a job for experts. Policy is another matter. What we need to understand is the simple principle of the money system, and, the following statement by the Earl of Tankerville, a Member of the British House of Lords, is as lucid a statement as I have yet read. He has stated:
Pen-and-ink money - bank credit - functions as money today, and, because the private banks only lend this money, and charge the community interest on it, a small but powerful group are obtaining control of all the real assets by a confidence trick which is without parallel in the history of civilisation. It is of interest to note the remark of Mr. Beaufort Pearce, Chairman of Lloyd’s Bank, who said in Melbourne, as reported in the “National Bank Monthly Summary” for December, 1934, that no capital is necessary to start a bank. The “Sydney Morning Herald,” of April 5, 1935, published the following:
The trading banks of Australia increased their total assets by over £298 millions from 1910 to 1935. The harder the community works the faster the total debts to the banking system increase. War only intensifies the pawning of the nation still further. THE FUTILITY OF THE PARTY SYSTEM Having clarified the point that the immediate and urgent task confronting Australian democracy is to demand, through parliamentary representatives, that the nation, and the nation alone, shall be the initial owner of all money, let us see how the people can try to have this policy implemented. One of the greatest contributions to the cause of true democracy is to be found in that monumental, work, “The Party System,” published in 1912 by Hilaire Belloc and Cecil Chesterton. As appropriate now as when it was written, this critical analysis of the party system of government should serve as a finger post, indicating the line of action we must take. To quote:
If true democracy is to become a reality, the present Party tyranny must be removed. Sovereignty and initiative must be restored to the people, who will, at all times, frame their own policy. For too long centralised groups have been telling the people what they think will be good for them. The time is long overdue when the electors must state what they think will be good for themselves. At the best, the Parties only represent sectional interests, which divide the people; one group believing that they can only get some advantage if more can be taken away from another section of the people. How futile in a world of plenty! But, then, all the Parties tell us that there is a shortage of funds. Apparently, they believe that there is naturally a fixed amount of money, and that, because some do not have enough, then some must have too much. We have seen how the party system is undemocratic. Apart from this is the failure of the parties to get any worth-while results for the particular sections they are supposed to represent.
We have not far to look for the failure of these Parties. They all make the same excuse. The country is “short of funds.” Those who control the funds, therefore, control the Governments - whatever the Party label. Possibly the most open admission of this fact was made by the late Prime Minister, Mr. J. A. Lyons, prior to the 1937 Federal elections, when he said, in the Adelaide Town Hall: “The banks had confidence in my Government, and we were able to carry on.” (Reported in Melbourne “Argus.”) What hypocrisy, under these circumstances, to talk about democracy. Section 51 (a) of the Constitution Act of Australia, gives the Commonwealth Government sovereign power over its own money supply. While we put our faith in parties which do nothing but divide the people, instead of uniting and demanding results, nothing will be done. As a matter of fact, the following quotation will graphically indicate that the party system, is part of the approved method used by Finance to frustrate the people. The “United States Bankers’ Magazine” of 1892 says:
THE DICTATORSHIP OF MONEY Edmund Burke, the great British statesman, once said: “The people never gave up their liberties but under some delusion.” For the benefit of the busy reader, I have carefully selected quotations, from well-known authorities, clearly revealing the tremendous influence of the Money Power. These quotations speak for themselves:
HOW TO MAKE DEMOCRACY EFFECTIVE One leading scientist has said “that definition is the breath of science.” In the realm of political science the necessity of defining democracy has been long overdue. In a democracy power should reside in the electors. One might therefore ask why the electors are not using that power to get what they want. The fact is that the function of the elector has been entirely misunderstood. He is asked to choose between technical programmes, or in other words, he is an arbitrator. Now in this respect, “one man, one vote,” seems obviously absurd. It is quite ridiculous to agree that a typical waitress or a professor of Greek can ably sum up the pros and cons of such things as “quotas,” "nationalisation,” or for that matter, upon the technique of how the present obsolete money system should function. But as any dictionary will indicate, democracy is the root of power, not judgment. It is power which should be drawn from the elector’s will, not judgment from his intellect. That is the common ground upon which all men can meet. All of us, whether professor or waitress, businessman or farmer, want the same results. We want the security and freedom which the modern world could easily give us. Obviously then we must use the power which we possess as electors to unite upon a demand and tell our members of Parliament what results we want. If we desire that sufficient purchasing-power be created for the purpose of allowing the people access to the actual or potential plenty of this country, without further debt or taxation, then we must demand it by forwarding a signed demand-form to our Member of Parliament. In other words the electors in each electorate must organise their demand on a non-party basis, give their Member of Parliament clear instructions as to what they want, and let him understand that they are not concerned with his Party label - that unless he does what a majority of his electors tell him they will vote him out at the next election. Members of Parliament are only interested in one thing: They want to know how much 'voting power they have behind them' in order to keep their seats. If the electors shows them quite clearly that they will support them irrespective of Party just so long as they do as they are told then control of the Member will be removed from the Party-machine and restored to the electors. Most Members will welcome a move similar to this. They desire to be individuals not mere machines, voting as a Party tells them. Until the electors organise behind their sitting Member on a non-party basis true democracy will remain a myth. Should any Member refuse to do as he is told then the electors will vote him out at the next elections. The next man will then be inclined to do as he is told. A threat of votes is the only thing which impresses Members of Parliament. No matter how much a Member may desire reform while he is controlled by a Party instead of by the people, his position is hopeless. The responsibility lies with the people and a study of the great reforms in history clearly indicates that Parliament never initiates a reform. It only puts its name to it after the people demand it. As a further illustration of the ridiculous manner in which the nation is governed at the present time, possibly the best analogy which can be utilised is to briefly look at the manner in which the running of an ordinary trading company is conducted. The company is owned by its shareholders, who by their votes, periodically elect a number of representatives to direct the company's affairs and get results. These directors are chosen not so much for their technical knowledge of the company’s manufacturing process as for their reputation for integrity, common sense, and general business ability. The directors then proceed to appoint sectional managers, who in turn select the technical staff for their various departments - engineers, chemists, accountants, salesmen and so on. The business is now run on a basis of getting results. The principle involved is that of personal responsibility, resting ultimately with the responsibility of the directors to the shareholders. And the shareholders are interested in one thing and one thing only, and that is results. If the directors fail to get results the shareholders remove them.The same procedure should take place in our national affairs. Let us consider ourselves as political shareholders in Australia Unlimited. We have our national board of directors - Parliament. But from a common-sense and business viewpoint, how futile is the administration of the nation! We elect a board of directors who are openly pledged to oppose each other on every major issue, and who tell the shareholders what they think will be good for them. Furthermore, under the present ideas of administration, they are also expected to be technical experts, with results which are heading towards chaos. Could we possibly imagine any business running satisfactorily if the directors openly opposed each other, imposed their will upon the shareholders and started entering the factory and telling the technical experts what to do? Still further, can we imagine the shareholders voting at shareholders’ meetings on the technical manner in which the company should be run? The whole idea would be absurd and the company would soon be in a chaotic state. Well that is exactly what we have been doing in our national affairs and it is hard to visualise anything more chaotic than our present conditions. And there is every indication that this state of affairs is going to get worse unless we decide that the present administration of the nation is wrong. As mentioned we must immediately start demanding results from our national directors and hold them responsible for getting results or getting out. They in turn call in the necessary experts and in turn hold them responsible for getting results. To sum the position up: Experts must be removed by Parliament if they fail to get the results which the people want. Failure by the Members to get results will also mean their removal, while failure by the electors to demand the results they want will also hasten their own “removal” - either through poverty or wars, which are products of the system we tolerate. In the last analysis the electors have no one else to blame but themselves. They get the results they deserve. Their slogan in future should be: DON'T BLAME YOUR M.P. - TELL HIM. PARLIAMENTARY SYSTEM A FRAUD UNDER PARTY POLITICS One of the most trenchant criticisms of party politics and their effect upon the parliamentary system of democracy that I have yet read was made by Captain H. M. Rushworth, ex-New Zealand M.P., in September, 1939. He was addressing a large gathering of Waiketo farmers at Ngaruawakia. To quote:
DEBT AND TAXATION The present financial policy will ultimately mean that private financial groups will have the whole world in pawn – unless a halt is called. The private creators of money are not very concerned about the repayment of the debt. If the people can be perpetually kept in debt, they can be more easily enslaved through the subtle power of taxation required to pay the interest on the debt. The great American democrat Abraham Lincoln, recognised this. The following passage from the London "Times," written after the American Civil War is very interesting on this point:
Lincoln was assassinated by a tool of the Money Power; also President Garfield who carried on the struggle for financial freedom which Lincoln initiated. Around the history of debt a long and interesting story could be written - amusing too, if, in spite of everything, you still possess a sense of humour. Roberto R. Doane, in a short history of debt, says: “The world debt increased 47 per cent during the 17th century, 466 per cent during the 18th century, 12,000 per cent during the 19th century.” Where is it going to end? Well, it’s not going to end while the present system continues. The 1936 Official Year Book showed that the Net Revenue of the State Railways throughout Australia for 1935, after paying expenses, was £11,680,320, available to meet Interest, £12,746,007 – and this does not include exchange. For the five years to that date the total losses amounted to over £20,000,000, mainly due to interest charges. The N.S.W. Department of Main Roads annual report for 1936 discloses that figures in respect of the Sydney Harbour Bridge, where, out of a total of £467,160 expenditure for 1935-36, 79.45 per cent was expended on interest and exchange. The Royal Commission on Banking, Clause 32, shows that out of total taxation, States and Commonwealth, of £99 million for 1936, £51 million was paid out in interest. No matter what you do or where you go, the subtle grasp of taxation cannot be escaped. If you go to the pictures or other amusement you pay an amusement tax. You pay taxes on everything, from the time you are born until the time you are dead - and even after you are dead if you leave enough for the Government to tax. An interesting statement in connection with this taxation swindle was made a few years ago by no less a person than Sir Josiah Stamp, Director of the Bank of England. He said:
ELECTORS MUST DEMAND RESULTS — NOT METHODS We have already seen that most of the misunderstanding about democracy as a form of Government has arisen because the people have been misled into believing that they must become economic experts. Apart from the various Parties and their platforms, which not even all the Party candidates understand, we have many schools, of reform. This aspect of the subject is so important that I will elaborate still further. Once every three years the people are asked to make their choice between alternatives, which are all alleged methods of getting the one result which everyone wants, broadly speaking; economic security at the highest level physically possible, plus individual liberty. At least, Party candidates assure us that they are desirous of these results - and many - others which they think we should desire. The simple idea of asking the electors what they think would be good for themselves never seems to enter the heads of these candidates. Even supposing that it was the job of the elector to choose between offering methods, which it is not, what a task would confront him! The absurdity of electors deciding the technique of improving the economic machine will be very quickly appreciated when it is realised that at the present time there are at least 24 major schemes before the public. This was declared to be the case by a meeting held by the British Science Guild in association with the Engineers’ Study Group on Economics in London on May 16, 1935. In the following resolution, adopted at an earlier meeting, the Group defined their starting point: “We, as a representative group of engineers and scientific workers, are dissatisfied with the fact that the community is not enjoying a standard of living and endowed leisure commensurate with the potential advance for which science and technology are responsible, and are meeting to discuss why the paradox arises, and how it can be resolved.” And did this group discover how the paradox can be remedied? An extract from the report of the first year’s work, as reprinted from “The Engineer,” of May 24, 1935, is very interesting on this point. After an exhaustive survey of‘ the 24 schemes, it concluded as follows:
Surely this is sufficient to indicate to the average man that it is not his job to decide between all these schemes. And, as this summing up so truthfully points out, the only people who profess to know are the supporters of the particular schemes - and they dissipate most of their energies in fighting amongst themselves as to which is the best technique to be used. We see again the old principle of divide and rule. How farcical! What would the people of Victoria have said if, when the State Electricity Commission started at Yallourn, they had forced the people to make a choice as to the best turbo-alternators, etc., offering. The people would have rightly regarded the procedure as ridiculous. And the same applies to every other phase of our lives. We hold experts responsible for getting desired results, and if they fail to get results we have them removed. We do not set ourselves up as wireless experts, sewerage experts, or bridge-building experts. And yet we are expected to be economic experts. It is the job of the electors to cease arguing about methods, which we are hopelessly divided upon, and to unite in demanding those results which we all know are both feasible and desirable. Real democracy reverses the present procedure, wherein we have various groups coming before the people and telling them that this or that is good for them. Real democracy offers a mechanism through which people can start demanding from Parliament that which THEY THINK WILL BE GOOD FOR THEMSELVES. Whether it is good or bad for them is their own concern, it is not for anybody else to dictate what they desire. It is for them to express their own desires. THE INSTITUTION OF PARLIAMENT We have seen the futility of the electors concerning themselves with the technical administration of our economic system. When the investigation along these lines is taken a little further and applied to our present political system, we begin to see how Parliament has been perverted from its original purpose. As to why Parliament exists, there appears to be the utmost confusion of thought at the present time. The same applies to members of Parliament; and, contrary to the true conception of democracy, Parliament has been so perverted from its proper function that we find it imposing its will upon the electors instead of the electors imposing their will upon it. In a truly democratic society Parliament is not an institution to impose its will upon the people. It is an institution for them to impose their will upon it. It is in the people that democracy, that sovereign power should reside. Reference to Parliament calls to mind how Walter Murdoch, in one of his delightful essays, compares Parliament with a gadget, and suggests that we immediately start to make use of it. To quote the late F. F. Gould, whose work for democracy in England must serve as an inspiration to all democrats, “The correct perspective is to regard Parliament as a typewriter tapped by the almighty voter.” The original idea of Parliament was a meeting place for the populace, and possibly the nearest approach to this was the old Greek idea of a free, deliberative assembly. However, it is obviously ridiculous for several million Australians to meet at Canberra. We therefore send along individuals to represent our wishes and our desires - at least, that is the theory of government by the people; although, as we have seen, it is not an actuality at the present time. Following the above line of reasoning, it will be readily seen that the sole reason for a member of Parliament is purely functional. If his own opinions are contrary to those of a majority of his electors, he must be prepared to advocate the views of his electors or resign. He is the paid servant of the people, and must realise that his job is to re-present the wishes of those who pay him, and press vigorously for their fulfilment. However, if he is expected to represent the demands of his electors, as distinct from the demands of his party, it is quite clear that his electors must inform him clearly what results they want, and also show that they are prepared to support him, irrespective of parties, as long as he presses for those results. In other words, the people should, as pointed out earlier, frame their policy and send members of Parliament to Parliament to re-present that policy and see that the administrative machinery is put into operation so that that policy is implemented. CAN THE "EXPERTS" GET RESULTS? In view of some of the past efforts of our economic experts, some people are naturally sceptical about the suggestion that we leave the technique of implementing our policy in their hands. To some extent one must admit that this attitude is quite justifiable, and it must be admitted that some of our experts in the past have uttered undiluted nonsense. However, quite a few people feel that our experts know better, but are dependent for their livelihood and prestige upon the very interests we are attacking. Of course, the ideas incorporated in our educational system have been mainly based on scarcity. Most well-informed experts now recognise the problem as one of abundance, and there are so many well-informed groups or individuals who state that they have a solution, that the obvious thing is for the electors to demand that the Government call in responsible experts immediately and hold them responsible for getting the existing or potential plenty distributed to the people. During peace or war, what is physically possible must be made financially possible. It must be pointed out in fairness to some of the criticised experts that the main responsibility for apparent failure must rest with the people, who have never wielded their power, and have thus allowed finance to dominate them and the experts. It is reported that Professor Copland has stated that he can do it “when they tell us.” Professor Copland has been subjected to considerable criticism for his part in the formulation of the Premiers’ Plan, and rightly so; but he certainly got results. Unfortunately, he got results for the wrong people. But they wielded the power, while the electors did nothing. The banks demanded the balancing of the budget. As the people made no demands, Professor Copland went ahead and devised a scheme to balance the budget. It certainly would have got that result, but the financiers began to see that the suffering it was causing might cause a revolt, and the scheme was not taken to its conclusion. However, the outstanding thing which emerges from this event is the fact that experts can get results under pressure. What the people must do is to organise greater pressure than vested interests, and demand the results which they want. If they allow themselves to be divided on the method, or even if they agree upon some method, they are pursuing a very dangerous course. If the method fails they then have only themselves to blame, but if they pin the responsibility on the expert to get the desired result, he will either have to satisfy the electors or lose his job. Even Professor Copland could devise a scheme, as is reported to have admitted, if he found that his career and well-paid job depended upon getting results. Should Professor Copland and his colleagues state that they cannot do it, then there are plenty who can. Real democracy depends upon individuals - representatives and experts - accepting personal responsibility. Power without responsibility has undermined democracy. The important issue confronting society at the present time is for the electors to have a clear conception of the proper relationship between the electors and the experts. We can well quote the words of Dr. Joad on this point. In his book, “Liberty Today,” he writes as follows: “Thus the apparently innocuous doctrine, that in a democracy the community should prescribe the end and the expert determine the means, results only too often in practice in conferring a charter upon the experts to impose upon the whole community in the name of means, ends upon which it has had no opportunity of expressing judgment, and this danger, I suggest, arises because in a modern community so-called means frequently reveal themselves on examination to be not means at all, but ends masquerading as means. The conclusion is not that the expert should not be consulted and used, but that required lest his employment should become a pretext for foisting upon the community measures which it has not willed.” This confusion between ends and means has been the downfall of democracy in the past, and those who govern through finance will take every care that the people are asked to pass their opinions about all sorts of means. But we must keep our eyes on the ends. In order to further elaborate upon this important point, let us take the building of the Sydney Harbour Bridge as an analogy. Although it would have been unlikely, suppose that the people who wanted the bridge had been asked to pass an opinion upon a technical method to be utilised in building it, and still further, suppose that a majority of them could have reached some agreement upon a scheme, what would have been the position if the bridge collapsed on the day it was finished? Obviously, the people would only have themselves to blame. But if they hold experts responsible, they are then in the position of judging on results, and results alone. The same applies in the economic sphere. The gap between production and consumption needs bridging with a sound money bridge. The electors must not fall into the trap of passing an opinion upon the technical method to be used, because, if the scheme they decide upon fails, they only have themselves to blame. This has happened time and time again in the past. If the Sydney Harbour Bridge had collapsed on the day it was finished, the people would have had no difficulty in agreeing that the experts had failed. Needless to say, the experts employed would have found it impossible to get another contract. The same attitude must be adopted to our economic experts, and we can rest assured that they will certainly get results when they know that their reputations and livelihoods depend upon it. Lord Horder, at an important gathering of leading Englishmen, gathered to hear Sir John Orr (whose outstanding work in connection with nutrition stirred Great Britain), said that he would lock up the Ministers of Health and Agriculture and Transport in a room together with the Governor of the Bank of England, and would not release them until they had solved the joint problem of food production and distribution. Under such an arrangement we can rest assured that a satisfactory scheme would be forthcoming before very along. Experts get results in every sphere in which we use them correctly. They will also function in the economic sphere if we exercise our prerogatives. Experts must be on tap - not on top. THE STATE AND THE INDIVIDUAL When dealing with the subject of Democracy it is essential that we clearly understand the proper relationship of the State to the Individual. The "trend” today is towards complete domination of the Individual by the State. The war has accentuated this "trend." One leading British sociologist has said: “Instead, then, of endeavouring to impose some abstract and immature organisation upon nations and upon the world, the first step would appear to be to examine the nature of nations. The first fact which seems incontestable about nations is that they are collections of human beings. Human beings can exist quite comfortably without nations, or States, but nations or States cannot exist without human beings. The only social philosophy which will allow the individual to attain his fullest development is that which religiously upholds the importance of the individual. This being the case, any system, whether it be economic or otherwise, which hinders the individual from obtaining happiness, must be altered, because systems are made for men – not men for systems. Those persons who are always telling us that the people don’t know what is good for themselves are upholding a philosophy which has always prevailed in varying degrees, but is now reaching its logical conclusions in modern society - which is fast becoming so centralised that individuals are slaves to such abstract gods as National Efficiency, The Nation and The State. Some people desire the present war to finish with a Super World State-Federal Union. This distinct “trend” is disturbing, and must be faced. As Tagore, the Indian philosopher, says: “The time has come when, for the sake of the whole outraged world, Europe should fully know in her own person the terrible absurdity of the thing called the Nation. The Nation has thriven upon mutilated humanity. Men, the fairest creations of God, came out of the National Manufactory in huge numbers as war-making and money-making puppets, ludicrously vain of their pitiful perfection of mechanism. Human society grew more and more into a marionette show of politicians, soldiers, manufacturers and bureaucrats, pulled by wire arrangements of wonderful efficiency...” That the individual both physically and mentally is being subjugated, needs no substantiation. The principles of true democratic government, if applied, would reverse this position to one in which every individual would be his own dictator. Most of the history of the social development of the human race can be written around the two conflicting schools of thought which have been mentioned above. Dating from the time of the Sophists of the early Greek civilisation, who were opposed to the authoritarian doctrine, the school of thought which has been opposed to all forms of centralisation and their consequent evils has found expression in many reform movements during the centuries, and is now finding its strongest expression in all “New Economic” thought. On the other hand, those who admire the virtue, so-called, of these things called National Efficiency, etc., have had their strong advocates from the time of Plato, who, in the eighth and ninth books of his “Republic,” launched a vigorous attack upon what he termed the inefficiency of democracy. And so, down the ages, the conflict has raged until, with the growth and monopoly of credit power, the enslavement of the individual has been carried to such a pitch that the forces of liberty have been hard pushed to keep alight the small spark of democracy. “Hitlerism” is the very embodiment of this pernicious philosophy. The outstanding problem which confronts society at the present time is to save the individual from enslavement, whether it be to power-crazed political gangsters; abstractions, such as “The State,” or the financial system. What is needed at the present time is a greater consciousness of the natural relationship between the individual and his institutions. If that can be obtained, quite a lot of tyranny from which man suffers today will pass away, and we will recognise that the advice, “The Sabbath was made for man, and not man for the Sabbath,” was not mere sentimentalism, but a brilliant maxim of social and political organisation. Here are two relevant quotations that should be noted. The first is from “The Soul of Man Under Socialism,” by Oscar Wilde. He wrote:
The second quotation is from an article in the Halifax (Nova Scotia) “Chronicle”:
Both Nazism and Communism look at life from a purely materialistic basis. Human beings are mere pawns in the economic game. Life is a matter of mechanics, and a perfect society is a perfect machine, designed and made by a Little coterie of super-men, who call themselves the State. Individuals are mere cogs in that machine. If individuals or groups of individuals do not fit into the society devised, then the State must step in and with the impersonality of a surgeon wielding his knife, excise them from the body politic. They call it ‘liquidating’ or ‘purging.’ But it has not been done with the cold impersonality of a surgeon. It has been done rather with the deliberate cruelty of a gangster exercising his sadistic power and impulse. It is doubtful if any blacker pages of history have been written than those of the last few years, which have seen the doctrines of materialism taking the shape of totalitarian States, with their claims to absolute control over the entire life of the individual. Any system which begins successfully to use man as a means rather than an end becomes a juggernaut crushing out of life all human freedom and value. The fundamental error of these ‘systems’ is their denial of the truth that, ‘man does not live by bread alone.’ His origin is more than biological, and his needs are more than material. He cherishes ideals and visions in preference to bread. Such men do not dream of a world of static perfection but of an evolving, expanding world in which human personality is attaining ever new reaches of freedom and fulfilment. In regard to the State and all other institutions, they assert the great principle laid down 1900 years ago in the words, ‘The Sabbath was made for man, and not man for the Sabbath.’ In the days when those words were spoken religion had made ritual requirement take precedence over human need. As a result religion had become soulless and inhuman. Likewise, when the State becomes absolute, it becomes merciless and intolerant.” DEMOCRACY AND THE STATE Even in the totalitarian countries such as Germany, the fundamental urge for freedom still exists - as witnessed by the following article, which was published, prior to the outbreak of war, in “Freies Deutschland,” the illegal organ of the German Opposition:
The possibility that a conspiracy against the rights and liberties of the peoples is in existence must be seriously considered, for its symptoms appear, not only in the totalitarian States, but even in those States which still pass as democratic. It is therefore, a duty for all who have at heart man’s freedom and the cultural and material progress which is so closely bound up with it, to combat every representation. According to the totalitarian view of life man serves the State. In a democracy the State serves man. This latter rests upon a Greek, European, New Testament, Christian conception. The first upon an ancient Egyptian, Asiatic, Old Testament, ancient Jewish one. In Germany even the scapegoat of the Old Testament has appeared again. That Judah itself has become the scapegoat cannot, however, be represented as justification of a 3000-year-old piece of brutality. In order to be better able to pass judgment upon these two views of life, it is necessary to be clear about the purpose of all institutions and associations, such, for example, as the State. In a country which is developing in a natural manner there are athletic clubs, music societies, tennis clubs, etc., in which certain people associate in order to exercise, to sing, or to play tennis. They associate in order to do this better, and perhaps more cheaply. By means of voluntary submission to a few rules, they receive individual advantages which make possible or easier for each one exercise, music, or tennis. The association exists only to serve the members. As soon as a member no longer wishes to associate he has perfect freedom to withdraw. A tennis club, which, by compulsion, consisted of footballers, would be abominable. Now, the State is just such an association, if on a somewhat larger scale than the associations which have been mentioned. It is quite natural for there to be many small associations which are generally concerned with questions of tastes and aims which exist in only a few people. The greater the field of interest the greater the association. In this present world of specialised work in every sphere there are in all countries three conditions necessary for the existence of the State: Politico-military security, the possibility of the market for its own production, and the possibility of sharing, according to desire, in the enjoyment of the products of others. The State must therefore offer to the individual protection against attack from a neighbouring State, and must be so organised economically that every citizen can give of his best to every other one, and receive from him food and luxuries. The State in itself is a pure abstraction. It is a question of an association of a great number of human beings who endeavour, by this means, to achieve the necessary military and economic security. Individual has joined with individual, people have formed States, because only by this means could co-operation be achieved. The State is a means which was invented, or simply developed, in order to serve its members. St. Francis Assisi said: “Means elevated to an end is a sin”; and he was right. The State is only a means. The fundamental misconceptions of today have their roots in that struggle between man and institutions which is being waged before our wondering eyes. On the one side are men with their just aims; on the other are institutions, means, abstractions. The individual who has once grasped this knows at once on which side he must stand - and act. Unfortunately these people mentioned above, who have conspired against humanity, prevent the majority of their victims from obtaining a clear picture of the true conditions. We cannot possibly know the real goal of mankind; but whatever it may be, it is to be achieved most rapidly and most effectively through the free development of the character of every individual human being. Such development is only possible within a democratic State. In the true democracy, as in every other association, the aims and objects of the State are subject to the supervision and authority of the citizens. This State must be served by a functioning aristocracy; the masses have no right to meddle with means, much less to prescribe means. The body politic lays down what is to be achieved, and the aristocracy of officials, industrialists, etc., must know how the goal can best be reached. This aristocracy however, has absolutely no right to impose upon the body politic a goal which has not been confirmed in democratic fashion. The goal is to be determined, even dictated, by the citizens. To attain the goal is the duty of the aristocracy. Ends and means must remain separated; the distinction between them must be kept brilliantly illuminated. Such a State must, however, exhibit not only spiritual, intellectual and political freedom, but also economic freedom. It has already been stated that the advances in purely material fields, such as science and industry, the ways and means of adapting the forces of nature to the service of mankind have made it possible for every citizen to enjoy a considerable measure of economic freedom, to be set free from want and economic subjection. In spite of the possibility no such State yet exists - this must be the next goal of a free mankind. Political power must be transferred absolutely to the people, so the last word rests with the individual in his totality. Economic independence, however, is a pre-requisite for the exercise of political power. To reach this goal a struggle is essential. In many countries this struggle has been raging for 20 years, in circumstances which are opening the eyes of more and more people, and making them see that the whole future of mankind hangs upon the victory. The front-line fighters on the side of humanity must, however, be clear in their own minds as to what the goal is, how the enemy fights, and, above all, what democracy really is.” THE CAMBRIDGESHIRE EXPERIMENT At the 1936 general elections in Great Britain an experiment in political strategy took place with remarkable results. This was in the early days of the application of the ideas we have been dealing with. This experiment proved beyond all reasonable doubt that the average member of Parliament can be controlled by his electors, organised along the lines of what has come to be known throughout the British Empire as the “Electoral Campaign.” About two months before the elections, an address was delivered at Cambridge by Professor Soddy, to an audience of professors and students, including many eminent scientists. Soddy is known to all students of science, and in that sphere has contributed valuable work on various subjects. In the realms of economic reform, Soddy has also contributed some valuable work, and one of those rare scientists who realise that all their work in the scientific field will not benefit humanity while control of the money supply remains in the hands of private individuals. In the address mentioned, Soddy used elaborate charts and diagrams to explain his thesis, but towards the end of the meeting he dropped a bombshell.
In answer to a question as to what he had to offer, Soddy told them about the electoral campaign. As a result of this meeting, the Cambridgeshire Electoral Campaign Committee was formed, with members ranging from unemployed to scientists. It was only six weeks to the elections. Letters were sent to the two candidates for the constituency of Cambridgeshire. They were asked whether they would be prepared to act promptly on the floor of the House for the abolition of poverty, if a majority of the electors signed written demands to that effect. (They were to do this irrespective of their own personal views or party affiliations. In other words, they were asked if they were prepared to take their orders from a majority of the electors instead of the party caucus.) The sitting member, Lieutenant-Colonel Rigby, who had held this seat for some considerable time with majorities of 45,000 votes, replied briefly and to the point. He returned the letter, marked “Not Interested.” He thought that he could afford to be not interested. But he had yet to learn the power of the electoral campaign. The other candidate standing was Professor White, who had lost his deposit at the three previous elections. When approached as to whether he would be prepared to do what a majority of the people wanted, he did not think very much of the idea of the campaign, but was a democrat, and agreed to the proposition. It was now only five weeks to the elections and the campaign was on. An intensive house-to-house canvass was proceeded with. A simple proposition was put to every elector. “Your sitting member is not prepared to advocate the abolition of poverty, even if a majority of you tell him to. Professor White will do so. If you believe in democracy here is an opportunity of expressing your wishes! And the result of the campaign? Well, the sitting, member (Lieut.-Col. Rigby) won again, but his previous huge majority was reduced to a bare five thousand. Under the circumstances this was a remarkable result, and definitely showed that the latent spirit of democracy in the electors can be aroused. However, the real result of the campaign was not seen until some three weeks after the election; and it will answer a question which is often met when outlining the electoral campaign. The question which arises mostly is: “Yes, but if we put a man in, and he doesn’t do the job, we have to wait three years to remove him.” Perhaps the following will answer this question thoroughly.“ Three weeks after being re-elected, the same Colonel Rigby, with years of political security in front of him, wrote to the Campaign headquarters and asked to be allowed to reconsider his previous decision that he was not interested in the demands of a majority of his electors. Undoubtedly he did some very hard thinking after the election, and realised that, although he still had a majority, it would only require a few more weeks of such campaigning to wipe out his majority. Although this experiment demonstrated what could be done, it was discovered that the big difficulty was to maintain interest. The people had never used their power. This was the big obstacle which confronted Electoral campaigners, and they set out to overcome this difficulty. The big task confronting those who seek to make democracy function is to restore political self-respect to the man in the street, who says: “What can I do about it?” He must be shown that he, together with his fellow electors, has supreme and continuous power. The electoral campaign is based on the democratic principle that the people govern every day - not once every few years. BRITAIN EXPERIMENTS WITH DEMOCRACY As in Australia, the electors of Britain have had to be slowly educated in the exercise of their power by small-scale trials. In other words, they are like a man who has never ridden a bicycle. He cannot immediately go for a 20-mile spin. He learns his power and control by easy stages. And so with the electors. They are learning their power in easy stages, and, in small examples, where they can quickly feel their power. They will quickly pass from local issues to national issues. Democrats in Britain in the early stages of the electoral campaign concentrated on getting the people demanding better roads, etc., from their councils and local bodies. In 1937, the ratepayers of Britain gained one of their first great victories. The British House of Commons decided to have a revaluation of land throughout Britain. This would have meant a rise in rates - a subtle way of extracting more financial tribute. The policy of “passing the buck” to municipal councils, of both debt increases and the resulting taxation increases is a policy which has been increasingly pursued in both Britain and Australia. The first centre where the rates were to be increased was Sheffield. Here, as elsewhere, it was quite obvious that a majority of the people were opposed to the rise. But, apart from trying to fight the matter in the courts (a very costly procedure) the ratepayers knew of no method by which they could do very much about the matter. The electoral campaigners suggested that if a majority of the ratepayers were opposed to the increase they should demand that the Council vigorously oppose it - otherwise ratepayers would remove the present councillors at the first opportunity. Within a few weeks 50,000 people signed demand-forms to the effect that there must be no rise in rates, and no reduction in social services. As a result, the Sheffield council was forced to capitulate, and the chairman of the finance committee published a statement that there would be no increase in rates. And this campaign only cost the ratepayers a few pounds for stationery. All that was required was the application of a little democratic pressure. Other centres quickly followed this lead, and more victories took place, with the result that the campaign looked like sweeping through the whole of Britain. The result of this was that Sir Kingsley Wood announced in the House of Commons that there would be no revaluation of land in Britain until 1940. Public opinion won. (Of course, now that Britain is at war, the Government has a plausible excuse for directly taxing the people.) In February, 1938, Belfast ratepayers prevented an increase in their rates by the simple expedient of signifying to their councillors that the rate was not to be increased. The demand was signed by 20,000 ratepayers. So successful has this strategy been in showing the ratepayers their power in unity, and particularly in revealing to them the manner in which the greater proportion of their rates goes to pay the interest bill on money lent to the councils by the banks, which money was a costless creation by these allegedly beneficent institutions, that the official banking journal, “Branch Banking,” in July, 1938, told branch managers that they were no longer to enter into any discussions on the creation of credit, “as there are now enough substantial quotations in existence to prove even to the uninitiated that banks can, and do, create credit. . . .” Real democracy means that leadership must always come from the people. The application of this principle of British democracy was again successful early in 1939. In 1938, the Government was endeavouring to organise a scheme for billeting evacuees from the city on to country people during war emergency. Public opinion was opposed to the idea, and the suggestion of building proper camps was enthusiastically accepted. The Government at first opposed the idea, but, after the electoral campaign principles were utilised for a few months, the Government submitted and voted one million pounds for the camps. They have since proved their worth. The bombing of London provided another graphic illustration of leadership coming from the people. The British Government was asked, time and time again, to maker money available to build more underground shelters for the people. In spite of the urgent need, it didn’t do it, and furthermore, the people were to be prevented from using the underground railways for shelter, However, with the ‘blitzkrieg” at its worst, the people utilised their sovereign power, and commandeered the underground railways. The Government was forced to submit. If the British people are to win this war for themselves, and not for the financial institutions, they must obtain control of their institutions and develop those fundamental principles of British democracy which have been the basis of British culture. THE STORY OF THE AMERICAN "PINK-SLIP" STRIKE One of the best modern examples of how public opinion can get results is to be found in the history of what is known in America as the “Pink Slip” strike. Approximating, as it does, the same tactics as the Electoral Campaign, it offers further refreshing evidence that the members of Parliament are the servants of the electors, and can be made to yield to a clearly-stated demand. This campaign took place in America in 1935, and the writer takes his factual material from the “Saturday Evening Post,” of June 8, 1935. The “Post’s” article was also condensed in the “Reader’s Digest,” of August, 1935. The “Pink Slip” ‘law was quietly introduced into the Revenue Bill of the American Congress in 1934, but it was not until early in 1935 that the average taxpayer read the pink slip which accompanied his income-tax form. Briefly, the idea of the slips was to record the intimate details of each individual’s income; to exhibit every taxpayer to a sort of fiscal fan dance. Most of the taxpayers voiced their protests to their associates, but beyond that it did not appear that any protest would be made. Hearing these casual protests, Mr. R. Pitcairn, chairman of the "Sentinels of the Republic," immediately wrote to many people in many parts of the States. The following events can be best described in the words of Pitcairn himself: “I decided to do something about the ‘Pink Slip.’ As a result, the Sentinels of the Republic swung into action. Our first step was to mail 12,000 letters to men throughout the United States. ‘Do you want this inquisitorial income-publicity law repealed?’ we asked. In order to make the resentment of the taxpayers heard, we proposed that each recipient:
The letters brought immediate responses to us, and started a deluge of protests on their way to Washington. The‘Pink Slip’ rebellion was on. Hundreds of thousands of protest forms were printed, signed, and sent in from all over America. By this time our mailing list had reached amazing proportions. Heads of professional groups - architects, lawyers, engineers - in many cases asked us to circularise their whole membership. Editorial writers, columnists, and commentators joined in the general attack. Before the campaign ended we had distributed more than half a million each of the forms: ‘I protest against this outrageous invasion of my right of privacy.’ We used the wires, too. The mail of Senators and Representatives was daily swelling with protests from the people. A few weeks later Representative Doughton reported on the Repeal Bill, and on March 11 the House passed it by a three-to-one vote. We had now won our first battle. We next faced the Senate and its Finance Committee. Shortly the Bill was reported favourably from the Committee to the Senate. Then, suddenly, a real threat loomed. We were told that Senate supporters of the ‘Pink Slip" law were planning a neat piece of Parliamentary strategy that would avoid consideration of the Repeal Bill. That called for quick action. We immediately got a new “Pink Slip’ protest out, and once again the mailbags swelled with hundreds of thousands of letters of protest. On March 29 the Bill was repealed by a vote of 53 to 16. Public opinion had tapped the Congressional sense of realism.” Now, what does it all prove? Well, it proves that the power of organised public opinion need not wait for elections to repeal legislation which a majority of the electors do not want. Similarly, a majority of the electors can get any desired legislation if they will only unite and demand it. That is the very essence of democracy. It does not fail when tried. TWO LOCAL EXAMPLES OF DEMOCRACY Here in Australia, the idea of real democracy - the people having complete control over their own institutions was, as in England, introduced in a small way at first, in order that electors could quickly learn their power. Two of the best practical examples of the manner in which one or two enlightened citizens in a community can show the rest of the community how to use democracy come from Ayr, North Queensland. The first example was in connection with the water supply and sanitary conditions at the local school in 1936. While in Ayr in 1939, during a Queensland lecturing tour, I obtained the facts from local citizens. There was hopelessly inadequate provision for a large number of children in the sanitary conveniences, which were very dilapidated. There was no drinking water at the school with the result that many children had to take bottles of water to school from home. A real fear of the outbreak of an epidemic was often expressed by parents and considerable agitation took place about the matter. The usual futile methods were utilised for some time until a real democrat attended one of the local meetings of parents and told those present that they must tell their local State member by signed demand-forms, that they wanted immediate results or they would vote and work to remove him at the next elections. This was done, and thousands of demand-forms were circulated and signed by citizens. Public opinion was mobilised in a tangible manner, with remarkable results. The State member, a Labor politician, recognised the fact that he would have to do as he was told or risk being removed. He could no longer shelter behind his Party. The demands did not even have to be sent to Brisbane before results were forthcoming. In a letter dealing with this campaign, the democrat who instigated it, wrote:
Democracy does work! Having grasped the idea of democratic pressure the citizens were not slow in utilizing similar strategy to that employed in obtaining decent water and sanitary conditions at the local school.
Both the above examples clearly demonstrated that the electors can obtain control over their institutions - whether the institutions be local or national. HOW NATIONAL INSURANCE WAS DEFEATED IN AUSTRALIA The successful campaign conducted against the National Insurance Act provided the Australian people with the greatest experiment in true democracy that this country has ever witnessed. In a matter of six months, this campaign, conducted on non-party, decentralised lines, achieved more for the Australian people than the political parties have been able to achieve in 30 years. No matter what the party label of the Government, taxation has mounted higher and higher. But this campaign, conducted with relatively little finance - an important thing to remember in view of the interests we are fighting - has already saved the Australian people from millions of pounds of increased taxation. Those people familiar with the financial trends in Australia were not surprised when National Insurance first appeared on the horizon of Australian political thought. Under a system of finance whereby we borrow what is ours, and pay interest for the privilege of doing so, it was to be expected that more subtle methods of taxation would have to be devised. This is the great art of taxation today, and calls to mind the graphic statement made in the British House of Commons by that astute British statesman, William Pitt. Speaking on a taxation measure before the House of Commons, he said:
And so, under the guise of an insurance scheme, the Australian people were to see further attacks upon their already low standard of living. The manner in which the Act was forced through the House, in face of so much opposition, even from some members of the ruling coalition, was the antithesis of democratic government. But, even if the Labor Party had been in office the results would have been little better. The only thing upon which Labor differed from the self-styled United Australia Party was the method of extortion - which indicates how the people, under the Party tyranny have no alternative but to take their choice between the lesser of two evils. Politicians apart, it was obvious from the start that nobody wanted it. Both employers and employees, were decidedly antagonistic. By its compulsory nature it violated the constitutional freedom of the individual. Here was a position which would be an anomaly in any democratic country. A majority of the people were opposed to certain legislation, but, under the Party system of government, knew of no method by which they could do anything about it, except wait until the next elections, and then try another Party. In the meantime, of course, they would have to pay the taxation and be regimented by more bureaucracy. This was a unique opportunity to try pressure politics. It was pointed out to the electors that their immediate task was to bring their individual Member of Parliament under control, and to inform him by signed demand-letters that, unless he took active steps to have this Act repealed, they would vote against him at the next elections, irrespective of his Party label. This was started. The following demand-form was drawn up by Mr. F. C. Paice, of Melbourne, who first had several hundred copies duplicated for distribution where he worked:
The demand for these forms was such that larger quantities were printed. Some electors used slightly different wording, but the basic demand was the same. All over Australia the idea was taken up. The electors, for the first time in their political lives, were telling Members of Parliament what they (the electors) wanted, or, in this case, what they didn’t want. They forgot all about their party differences. For the first time in Australian history we saw the will of the electors crystallised by a tangible medium, and directed against the individual Member of Parliament, who was thus forced to accept personal responsibility. He could no longer hide behind his Party. One of the most remarkable features of this campaign was the manner in which the fundamental idea of democracy was also grasped within the Trade Union movement. Trade unionism, as originally conceived, was essentially democratic. Unfortunately, like Parliament, it has been perverted, with the result that, instead of Union executives being appointed for the sole purpose of giving the rank-and-file what it wants, they tell the rank-and-file what they think will be good for it. Without even consulting the rank-and-file, many of the Union executives started to spend Union members’ money in forming “Approved Societies” for implementing National Insurance. When Mr. Paice put his idea of the demand letter to the officials at the Melbourne Trades Hall he was told that nothing could be done as the Act was law. Mr. Paice replied by saying that the people were ultimately responsible for all laws, and, if they didn’t want this Act they had the constitutional power to have it repealed. Mr. Paice, in his campaign, met with surprising hostility from the Trades Hall, with the result that the rank-and-file of trade unionists in many cases started to assert their authority, and tell their executives that they, like Members of Parliament, were only paid servants. Naturally, the executives had to yield to the will of the rank-and-file. Democracy must work. Institutions must not be allowed to become more important than individuals. It would take too long to deal in detail with this nation-wide campaign which flooded Canberra with a deluge of hundreds of thousands of demand-forms. Slowly, but surely, as the pressure was applied, the attitude of Members of Parliament began to change, and a Cabinet crisis took place. However, under the pretext that owing to defence expenditure, the country “could not stand it,” it was definitely decided not to proceed with the scheme. Even Mr. R. G. Casey, Member for Corio at that time, who introduced the Act, was forced to alter his attitude – although in answer to Mr. Brennan, in the House, on September 22, 1938, Mr. Casey had said that the Government proposed to take no notice whatever of the electors. What strange views some of our politicians have on democracy! However, all the explaining in the world did not stop the constant flow of demand-letters, and one U.A.P. member, the late Mr. J. V. Fairbain (Flinders, Victoria) said at a public meeting in Frankston, March, 1939:
Possibly the best testimony to the influence of this campaign was given by one of the orthodox daily papers. The following report appeared in the Sydney “Sun”:
This was a most significant admission, although I find it hard to imagine how the electors can be the enemies of the politicians. If it is blackmail for the electors to demand results from those who are supposed to represent them, then I say that the sooner we have a lot more blackmail, the sooner we will get out of the present chaos. But, this Electoral Campaign is not blackmail. It is the only basis upon which to build real democracy. The time will come when the campaign against National Insurance will be regarded as an historic event. It taught us that we have no need to wait for Parties, or elections, to get results. The people can get results which a majority of them desire, if they will only accept their democratic responsibilities. PUBLIC OPINION AND THE COMMONWEALTH BANK ACT The Commonwealth Bank Act which the “Sun” referred to was brought down in the House of Representatives by Mr. R. G. Casey, on November 25, 1938. Let us briefly examine the events which led up to the introduction of this Act, the real object of the Act, and the campaign to defeat it. Until 1929 very few people in this country were familiar with the power of the Commonwealth Bank, and the manner in which this Bank, prior to 1924, had been used on behalf of the Australian people. In 1924 the Bruce-Page administration introduced legislation which gave control of the Bank to the Commonwealth Bank Board, dominated by nominees of the private trading banks. In 1920, Sir Denison Miller, Governor of the Bank, had utilised it to defeat the deflationary policy being introduced by the private trading banks. When the depression of 1929 was started, the Commonwealth Bank was impotent. However, although controlled by the private trading banks, it still belonged to the Australian people, and the Government had power to use it on behalf of the Australian people. Lacking the clear-cut demand of public opinion, nothing was done. The people were betrayed to the private financiers. The depression started many people investigating the financial system, with the result that, by the 1934 elections, the late Mr. J. A. Lyons (then Prime Minister) was forced to promise a Royal Commission on Banking in order to retain his seat. Although this Commission was comprised of men, noted for their orthodox views about money, it was forced to make certain admissions, the most important being as follows:
Here was an admission that the Commonwealth Bank, as the Central Bank in our Australian banking system, could issue all the money necessary for the nation’s needs for the mere cost of administration. It cost the Australian taxpayers £22,000 to learn what common-sense should have told them years before. Public opinion was now aroused all over Australia in demanding that these findings be discussed at Canberra and implemented. The next move by the financiers was to have the Commonwealth Bank Act Amendment Bill introduced, which, if passed, would mean their ownership of the Commonwealth Bank. The reader will notice that I say, “if passed.” Up to the time of writing, the campaign conducted against the Act has prevented it from being even brought before the House. On February 24, 1939, a demand form in connection with this matter appeared in the “New Times.” Electors were urged to get people to use similar tactics to those adopted against National Insurance. This campaign was much more difficult than the National Insurance issue, as the people, on the whole, knew very little about the Commonwealth Bank. However, a nation-wide educational campaign took place with the result that many different papers, belonging to different movements, published articles dealing with the matter, and urged electors to write to their respective members of Federal Parliament immediately. Once again hundreds of thousands of demand forms flowed into Canberra from all over Australia. After months of intense campaigning by Electoral Campaigners throughout Australia, Mr. P. C. Spender, then Assistant Treasurer, said that several Clauses in the Commonwealth Bank Act Amendment Bill would be deleted, owing to organised public opinion. However, even the modified Bill has not yet been introduced. This was another unmistakable victory for real democracy on non-party lines. THE STRUGGLE FOR DEMOCRACY IN CANADA Canada has long been recognised as being a danger spot to the financial oligarchy which seeks to make its world hegemony secure through the destruction of democratic institutions. A lengthy book could be written about the struggle to throw off financial domination which has been raging in Alberta for the past five years. The people of that Canadian province are more determined in their efforts than ever before and have organised public opinion behind their Members of Parliament. They left the implementing of their desires to the Aberhart Government during its first eighteen months in office, but nothing was done. Electoral Campaign tactics were then adopted, and the fight was on. Slowly but surely, in spite of the fact that the province does not enjoy autonomy in monetary matters, conditions were improved. Alberta has actually reduced its debt! The people returned the Aberhart Government with an overwhelming majority early in 1940. This was a surprise to those who took their views from the daily papers, and therefore believed that chaos reigned in Alberta. The lessons learnt in Alberta have not been lost on the rest of Canada. The Electoral Campaign idea had made such progress by 1938, that a special committee of the House of Commons, Ottawa, considered, and approved two proposals affecting rights never before touched in the electoral laws of the Dominion. The first would make it an offence for any Parliamentary candidate to sign a questionnaire or pledge binding himself to any specific course of action. The second would make it illegal for any candidate to pledge himself to promote the expenditure of public money on behalf of any persons or organisation. Both these extraordinary proposals were introduced by the Honourable C. G. Power. These measures would, of course, have the effect of placing the Member of Parliament beyond the control of his constituents, and there is little doubt that this was their primary, if not their only, intention. In the following extracts from the “Montreal Star's” report of the meeting of the special committee will be recognised the true aims of this suggested legislation:
Comment is unnecessary. When we hear of proposals such as these, we begin to realise what democracy is really up against. However, Canada, with the rest of the Empire, fights on; for all those things which we hope we British people can preserve from the present peril. HISTORY VINDICATES DEMOCRACY
Most people, when first hearing of the Electoral Campaign, regard it favourably, or otherwise, as some new revolutionary idea born of comparatively recent social and political developments. This is not altogether so. The fundamental principle underlying this campaign has been appreciated right throughout the ages, where men have fought for liberty and security. Some time ago, in an article by the English biologist, Dr. Tudor Jones, appeared a statement to the effect that there is no evidence whatever to suggest that the human being of the present day is, in any essential, cleverer or more able, than the human being of six or seven hundred years ago. A study of history, particularly the history of Scotland from the thirteenth to sixteenth centuries, indicates that the realities of statesmanship were as much appreciated then as they are now. These realities also appear to have been understood and utilised during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. The most vital reality to which I refer is the principle that, in association, individuals can get what they want. Nations are, primarily, merely associations for the good of those composing them. And, to quote one of Britain’s greatest sociologists of the present time, “The general principles which govern association for the common good are as capable of exact statement as the principles of bridge building, and departure from them is just as disastrous.” The totalitarian theory, which proclaims that the State is everything and the individual nothing, is a departure from those principles. It is a re-statement of the theory of the later Roman Empire, which, together with the financial methods by which it was maintained, led to Rome’s downfall, not by the conquest of stronger empires, but by its own internal weaknesses. This position seems to be developing very strongly in practically every country at the present time, and only a correct understanding of the power of organised public opinion focussed upon a commonly-agreed-on objective can prevent the threatening destruction of twentieth-century civilisation. That we can prevent that breakdown should be more readily appreciated if we make a survey of two of the most important reforms in British history, and understand the underlying reason for their ultimate success. HOW PUBLIC OPINION ABOLISHED SLAVERY Undoubtedly, one of the greatest reforms in the history of the British Empire was the Abolition of Slavery, and that reform is most graphically summarised in the words of one of England’s greatest living historians, G. M. Trevelyan, Regius Professor of Modern History in the University of Cambridge. The following extracts are taken from his book, “British History in the Nineteenth Century.” This summing-up is particularly illuminating, and emphasises the fact that Parliament cannot impede reform once the people are organised for it. It also shows that Parliament never starts a reform, but merely puts its name to it.
Thus we see how the use of democracy achieved one of the greatest reforms in modern history, in spite of vested interests, which were just as strongly entrenched as the interests we are fighting today. The shipping interests, for example, said that the Abolition of Slavery would wreck their business; while others said that such a reform would mean that Britain could never colonise the Empire. Many other arguments were brought forward, but the fact remains that in the year 1807 one of the most corrupt Parliaments that Britain has ever had was forced to yield to organised public opinion. And if public opinion can be roused to the same extent again, we will also see the abolition of the greatest slavery of all time - financial slavery. HOW THE BRITISH PEOPLE GOT THE VOTE In sequence of importance, the greatest reform next brought about in the history of Britain was when the British people first obtained the power to vote for their own representatives in 1832. This achievement further demonstrated the power of public opinion, as the people at this time had no vote with which to enforce this reform. Even though the House of Commons and the House of Lords knew that by putting their names to the Reform Bill it would put an end to many privileges they had enjoyed in the past, they were forced to yield to the determined demand of public opinion. Once again the story of this reform can be best told in the words of Professor Trevelyan:
This reform allowed the people to take a big step forward in political emancipation. Unfortunately, as we now realise, the people have not learned the correct use of the vote. Instead of using their votes to demand results, they have been cajoled into wasting them upon issues which are technical or of no fundamental importance, and keep the people divided. When the principles of real democracy are put into operation the people will use their votes to get whatever results they want: they will remove those individuals responsible for the administration of their affairs, unless the desired results are forthcoming. CONCLUSION “We must be free or die, who speak the tongue That Shakespeare spake; the faith and morals hold Which Milton held." - - “The British Heritage,” by William Wordsworth. In spite of its many faults, the Anglo-Saxon character is the last great bulwark against complete world-tyranny - tyranny which grows more and more violent. Gangsterism stalks unchecked throughout Germany, Italy, Russia, and other countries. The British people, who have led the world to freedom and social progress in the past, now face a challenge such as civilisation has never previously witnessed. We are not merely watchers in a great drama - we are actors, each capable of playing his part as the spirit moves him. Many are still apathetic actors; others are seized with the spirit which has manifested itself time and time again throughout British history and are prepared to take action. Today the demand goes out for a real victory for the British people and not a repetition of the last war - a war won by the financiers. These financiers, now organised on an international scale, are using the totalitarian powers to smash the British Empire and British institutions. If the Empire is to put forward its maximum effort, financial restrictions must be swept aside, bureaucracy and red tape thrown overboard, and a real will-to-win spirit encouraged. Electors must unite on one result - a result which they can all recognise. The following is a suggested demand form which electors might send to their Members of Parliament:
Public opinion must be mobilised to demand that victory for which we all yearn. Every individual must accept his responsibility and join the growing army of democrats - an army which marches towards the dawn of real democracy; an army with a purpose which has been the driving force in the British struggle for freedom. The growth of the democratic idea has been a living experiment from the time of Magna Charta - down through history: Watt Tyler, Wilberforce, Shaftsbury; people have taken the idea of democracy with them. The great British traditions of liberty and human dignity, expressing themselves in the language of our greatest writers and poets, go marching on. If those traditions are to be maintained and developed, the principles upon which I have outlined in this book must be put into operation - now. Will democracy survive? You, with your fellow-citizens, are called upon to make your decision. Surely the tongue of Chaucer, of Jane Austen, of Shakespeare, of Keats, of Shelley, will not become the language of an enslaved race? I do not believe it.
|